More on Medicaid MCO Tax Strategy & Other News of the Day

March 14, 2024

NYS Council members,

1)  We have updated the COLA letter on our Website in our Online Advocacy Center where you can generate a communication to your Assembly and Senate elected representatives, urging them to push for a ‘clean’ COLA provision (without restriction on how the funds can be used by eligible agencies) with just one click.  Please send letters AND continue to call/text lawmakers.  Our Website is:  www.nyscouncil.org  THANK YOU!

2)  The Fiscal Policy Institute (FPI) has done a useful analysis of the proposal in both the Assembly and Senate one-house budget bills to generate Medicaid funding by assessing a tax on managed care plans.   See more below.

3)  The Substance Abuse and Mental Health Services Administration (SAMHSA) is requesting a $612 million increase over 2023 funding for 2025, fyi. The agency is seeking additional funding for opioid response, community mental healthcare and the 988 lifeline. President Joe Biden proposed a $7.3 trillion budget March 11. The budget included several mental health initiatives, including those run through SAMHSA. 

Here are the five biggest line items in SAMHSA’s $8.1 billion proposed budget for 2025: 

  • $1.6 billion for state opioid response grants, a $20 million increase from 2023. 
  • $1 billion for a community mental health services block grant, including 10% set aside for programs for individuals with early serious mental illness, and 10% for prevention and early intervention for at-risk youth and adults with mental illness. 
  • $601 million, a $100 million increase from 2024, for administering and scaling the 988 lifeline. 
  • $450 million for community behavioral health clinics, including a request for authority to develop a process for accreditation of these clinics. The proposal is a $65 million increase from 2024. 
  • $413 million for state and local governments and nonprofit organizations to increase access to community mental health centers. 

Fiscal Policy Institute

Press Contact: Monica Klein, 917-565-0715,  press@fiscalpolicy.org

The Medicaid MCO Tax Strategy

How an obscure feature of Medicaid policy could generate $4 billion in revenue for New York

Read the full analysis

ALBANY, NY | March 14, 2024 — Following the release of the State Senate and Assembly One-House Budgets, the Fiscal Policy Institute released a new analysis on The Medicaid MCO Tax Strategy: How an obscure feature of Medicaid policy could generate $4 billion in revenue for New York. The analysis finds the legislatures’ proposal is preferable to the drastic cuts to home care and lack of support for safety net hospitals in the governor’s budget. These cuts would create a crisis in access to care for hundreds of thousands of New Yorkers. The best way to avoid these cuts in the long term would be through programmatic reforms like the elimination of the wasteful Managed Long-Term Care program and a more systematic approach to hospital funding reform, but these changes will likely take more than a single budget cycle. The MLTC reform in particular could save billions of dollars per year. An MCO tax to draw down more federal revenue is a smart way to bridge the gap in the meantime.

Key Findings

The Senate and Assembly one-house budgets propose a Managed Care Organization (MCO) provider tax that would be cost-neutral for the State, but would generate $4 billion in increased Federal Medicaid revenue.

This complex proposal, inspired by a recent move in California, may face regulatory challenges at the Federal level.

Despite these challenges, an MCO tax will allow the state to draw down significant federal funds at no cost to state taxpayers, avoid home care wage cuts, and set the stage for further reforms.

Overview

The debate over Medicaid spending in New York has rarely been more divided. Governor Hochul, in her executive budget, declared Medicaid spending growth unsustainable and proposed sharp cuts to home care spending, financially distressed hospitals and several other items, drawing sharp criticism from advocates and industry groups. Meanwhile, 1199 and the Greater New York Hospital Association are campaigning for significant rate increases for hospitals and nursing homes. 

The legislative one-house budgets come out firmly for higher Medicaid spending, restoring most of the governor’s cuts and offering significant rate increases. But how will they pay for it? The Senate and Assembly budget memos propose to raise $4 billion a year through an obscure mechanism: A tax on Medicaid managed care plans, the private insurance companies which administer most of the state’s Medicaid program. To quote the Assembly’s budget summary: 

The MCO tax generates $4 billion in receipts from Managed Care plans. This revenue [will] be used by the State to repay the tax obligation for each plan through their capitated rates. This repayment generates an additional $4 billion in federal funding to then be used by the State as the non-federal share of investments in the Medicaid program.

Despite appearances, this proposal won’t cost MCOs a dime. The Assembly and Senate are proposing to tax them while reimbursing them for the tax through a rate increase — and yet somehow this circular procedure will generate federal revenue. 

Provider Taxes in the 1980s: Generating Federal Revenue Out of Thin Air

Medicaid is jointly funded by the state and federal government. Specifically, in New York, for each dollar of State spending on Medicaid, the federal government kicks in a dollar of federal funds. The more a state spends, the more the federal government contributes. 

In principle, this system creates an opportunity for state governments. Suppose a state imposes a $100 tax on a given hospital, then spends that $100 on Medicaid payments to the hospital. When the money is spent as a Medicaid payment, it draws down another $100 in federal matching funds, so the hospital receives $200. The state has not lost any money (it taxed $100 and spent $100), but the hospital has gained $100 (it paid $100 in taxes and received $200 in Medicaid payments). Such a tax provides states with a way to effectively generate Medicaid dollars out of thin air, by imposing a “tax” on healthcare providers that ends up generating revenue for those same providers. 

Congress never contemplated this strategy when it enacted Medicaid in 1965, but by the mid-1980s, as states faced mounting fiscal pressure due to a weak economy and growing Medicaid rolls, arrangements like the one described became increasingly common. A state would impose a tax on, for example, nursing homes with high Medicaid utilization, spend all the revenue raised on Medicaid nursing home rates, and draw down a federal match on the spending — essentially funding Medicaid on the federal dime.

Of course, even a tax that generated “free” federal revenue in the aggregate might still cost money for some specific providers. A tax on all hospitals that was used to fund a Medicaid hospital rate increase would increase funding for the hospital industry overall, but hospitals with few Medicaid patients might pay more in taxes than they received from the rate increase. However, states had ways of structuring taxes to address this problem: for example, they might levy the tax only on providers with a high concentration of Medicaid patients (what we will call “high-Medicaid providers”), or make the tax proportional to Medicaid revenue. In some cases, states even guaranteed that every provider paying the tax would receive at least as much in rates as they paid in taxes, a so-called “hold harmless” provision.

The California Loophole

1991 reforms to provider taxes ensured that they would be an ongoing source of state revenue — and state-federal controversy. Provider taxes of various kinds are a near-universal feature of state Medicaid policy: 49 states and the District of Columbia have at least one provider tax, and these taxes generated 17 percent of state Medicaid funds as of 2018. Democratic administrations have tended to be more willing to approve state provider taxes than Republican administrations, and the use of provider taxes grew especially rapidly during the Obama administration. The Trump administration proposed regulations which would have significantly restricted the use of provider taxes, but these regulations were never finalized. 

Taxes on Managed Care Organizations (MCOs) have proven to be a particular site of conflict. Most states, including New York, administer their mainstream Medicaid programs through private insurance companies, or “managed care organizations.” States are allowed to levy provider taxes on MCOs and 18 states already do so. To comply with federal regulations, however, these taxes must be broad-based and uniform — that is, they must apply not only to Medicaid MCOs but to private insurance plans like those purchased by small businesses for their employees. States may seek a waiver of the broad-based and uniform requirements, but only if the tax is redistributive, moving money from the private insurance market to support Medicaid. 

These requirements would appear to set narrow limits on states’ ability to levy a politically palatable MCO tax. In order to tax Medicaid MCOs (which will support a tax since it will pay for itself in newly-generated federal Medicaid revenue), states must also tax private MCOs (which will not see a benefit from the tax and therefore oppose it). 

California in particular has long wrestled with these requirements. It imposed an MCO tax in 2010 that applied only to Medicaid MCOs, but CMS rejected this tax in 2014. The state passed a restructured tax in 2016, but this new tax was constrained by federal requirements and raised only a relatively modest $1.4 billion a year. Last year, however, California enacted legislation that greatly expanded its MCO tax, raising nearly $5 billion a year in federal revenue. The tax levies a charge per person on individuals covered by both Medicaid and non-Medicaid insurance in California, but the tax is set at $182.50 per person for Medicaid enrollees and just $1.75 per person for private insurance enrollees — a clear violation of the requirement that the tax be “uniform.” California was thus required to apply to the federal Center for Medicare and Medicaid Services (CMS) for a waiver of the uniformity requirement by proving that the tax is redistributive — moving funds from private insurance to Medicaid. 

On its face the tax is evidently not redistributive; virtually all the money it raises comes from Medicaid and is spent on Medicaid (drawing down federal matching dollars). But California found a way to structure its tax so that it complied with the technical statistical test of redistributiveness used by CMS — and so, in December of last year, CMS was forced to very grudgingly approve it. 

The New York State legislature appears to be taking inspiration from this approval: If California can do it, surely New York can too? This may well be the case, but it is important to recognize that CMS is extremely skeptical of the California plan. CMS’s formal approval letter is worth quoting at length (emphasis added): 

California’s tax on managed care organizations, due to its tendency to derive revenues from Medicaid, does not appear consistent with the definition of “generally redistributive”… California’s tax derives revenues mainly from Medicaid services (instead of non-Medicaid services) and uses these revenues as the state’s share of Medicaid payments. Accordingly, we are concerned that this tax program fails to be “generally redistributive in nature.” However, CMS is approving California’s request for a waiver of the broad-based and uniformity requirements because the state’s proposal meets the applicable statistical test… For the reasons described above, the result of the statistical tests, in these instances, do not appear consistent with either the definition of generally redistributive or reflective of the expected results based on the intended design of the statistical test. Therefore, CMS intends to develop and propose new regulatory requirements through the notice-and-comment rulemaking process to address this issue […] Please be advised that any future changes to the federal requirements concerning health care-related taxes may require the state of California to come into compliance by modifying its tax structure. 

In essence, CMS is saying that California’s tax violates the spirit of the regulations — it is not truly redistributive — but the state has complied with the letter of the law, so CMS must approve it. But there’s an important caveat: CMS adds that it now plans to update the relevant regulations in order to close the loophole California has used — and the new regulations would likely require California to repeal or alter its MCO tax. 

That news is not as bad as it may sound. California’s proposal was approved through 2027, and the state will get to keep the money it generates even if regulations change in the future. Meanwhile, new regulations can take several years to develop and implement and are subject to the vagaries of both politics and litigation. It is plausible that, if Biden is re-elected, his administration will decide not to tighten provider tax requirements after all. Meanwhile if Trump is elected, his administration will likely once again pursue a much more aggressive tightening of provider tax regulation — which will restart the regulatory clock and provoke widespread opposition. In the long term, it is quite possible that California will find its provider tax ruled noncompliant and will need to plug a $5 billion annual hole in its budget — but that will not happen until at least 2027, and possibly later.

California and the New York Model

Which brings us back to New York. It is likely that in proposing an MCO tax with “higher rates imposed on Medicaid Managed Care plans compared to non-Medicaid plans,” the legislature is looking to California for inspiration: California figured out how to generate more federal revenue for its Medicaid program, so why shouldn’t New York do the same? 

Given the lack of detail in the legislature’s proposal, it is difficult to evaluate whether this model would work in New York and how much revenue it might generate if it did. A specific concern in New York is how this new tax might interact with our Health Care Reform Act (HCRA) taxes, which already raise substantial revenue for Medicaid and which are “grandfathered in” to federal compliance through the D’Amato provision. Would CMS allow New York to leave HCRA in place and impose this new tax alongside it, or would imposing an MCO tax require a broader conversation about HCRA reform? The issue is complex in part because, unlike California’s model, HCRA taxes really are redistributive — they impose a higher rate on commercial insurance and use this to fund Medicaid services. And like California, New York might risk setting itself up for budget problems in the future if CMS tightens regulations on the MCO tax. 

Still, the legislature’s proposal is clearly preferable to the drastic cuts to home care and lack of support for safety net hospitals in the governor’s budget. These cuts would create a crisis in access to care for hundreds of thousands of New Yorkers. The best way to avoid these cuts in the long term would be through programmatic reforms like the elimination of the wasteful Managed Long-Term Care program and a more systematic approach to hospital funding reform, but these changes will likely take more than a single budget cycle. The MLTC reform in particular could save billions of dollars per year. An MCO tax to draw down more federal revenue is a smart way to bridge the gap in the meantime.

Read the full brief